Lenin was fond of the English saying: ‘Facts are stubborn
things’. The accuracy of many so-called facts may be disputable, but it can be instructive
to report on the facts published by official institutions of imperialism, ones
that nevertheless throw a not very flattering light on today’s realities. This
article is a complement to the ‘Imperialism by Numbers’ article I published on
this blog on 1 May. It is also an update to, and an extension of, some data I reported
in ‘What the “China Price” Really Means’, published on 4 June last year.
The first set of facts is shown in Chart 1. These are data
that cover average hourly compensation costs, where ‘compensation’ means not
only wages paid, but also the additional employer payments for social benefits
such as unemployment insurance, medical insurance, and old-age pensions. The source
is the US Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS), which carried out this analysis to
calculate for US corporations the total costs of employing workers in a range
of different countries. The details show that it is not only wages paid that
are higher in the richer countries; employee benefit costs are much higher too.
Chart 1 gives index numbers based on 100 equalling $34.74, the BLS figure for
the average hourly compensation paid to US manufacturing workers in 2010.
Countries’ labour costs are shown as bigger or smaller bars, with the height of
each bar proportional to the 100 level compensation cost in the US.
For China, average hourly
compensation costs are estimated at $1.65. This was less than 5% of the costs
of US manufacturing employees in the same year! Several years earlier, China’s
figure was closer to 2% of US costs, but recent sharp wage rises in China have
narrowed the gap a little. India and Sri Lanka have a still smaller ratio of US
compensation costs, near 4% and 2%, respectively. Labour compensation costs are
higher in the Philippines and Mexico, but Poland is the first country from the
low end of the chart that has compensation costs that are more than 20% of the
US level.
By contrast, the US,
Canada, Japan and the rich Europeans tower above all the other countries shown
in the chart. This group includes the so-called G7 countries, the major powers
still running the world economy. Switzerland, Belgium, Germany and France have
compensation levels more than 20% higher than in the US. One factor
influencing the country ranking is the value of a national currency in the
international market. However, the gap between the top ranked countries and the
bottom ranked ones is so large that this currency factor has little influence
on the overall distribution.
Surprisingly, the BLS’s
data do not include any African country. Perhaps this is a problem of getting
comparable statistics. For example, this is the reason that the BLS does not
include figures for China and India in its standard country comparison reports,
though it gives some information separately. However, Africa has also been a
less important continent for US economic expansion overseas than elsewhere, and
the BLS data focus far more on Europe, Asia and Latin America.
Chart 1: Relative International Labour Costs in Manufacturing, 2010
(Hourly
costs, US = 100 is $34.74, including non-wage compensation)
Sources and notes: US BLS. 2010 estimates based on
2007-08 BLS data are made by the author for China, India and Sri Lanka. Note
that 2-letter ISO codes are used as country identifiers, and that CH refers to
Switzerland, not China (which is CN).
Even the relatively minuscule labour costs for the poorer
countries exaggerate the actual earnings of millions of workers. The Indian
data are boosted by including only the so-called ‘formal sector’, that is the
sector made up of generally larger, more organised companies that have some
form of regulation and government supervision – including being included in
statistical surveys! By contrast, the ‘informal sector’ is unorganised, on a
much smaller scale and may include a family ‘business’ that consists of the
parents, children and dependent relatives. This sector is not included in most
data surveys, but it accounts for a large share of employment at much lower
wages than in the formal sector. The BLS reports that 80% of India’s
manufacturing employment is in the informal sector.
For China, the BLS calculations of hourly compensation do
include estimates for the ‘informal sector’. In Chinese statistics this is
listed under the heading of ‘town and village enterprises’ (TVEs), whereas the
larger, more regulated, sector is under the heading of ‘urban enterprises’. The
TVEs accounted for 70% of the total workforce, with 79.1 million workers
employed in 2006; the urban enterprises sector employed the other 30%, or 33.5
million workers. Not surprisingly, in 2008 the average hourly compensation was
just 82 cents in the TVEs compared to $2.38 in the urban companies.[1]
American and other foreign corporations will tend to set up
in the formal sector, and will likely be paying the ‘higher’ wages. But they
will still benefit from the mass of even cheaper labour from poor families who
work for them indirectly, either by providing services for the larger
companies, or by being what Marx called the ‘reserve army of labour’ for the
formal sector. The divergence in labour costs for countries other than China,
India and Sri Lanka may be less extreme. For example, South Korean costs are
just below half the US figure. But there is still a very big gap.
If we look at the broader economy, rather than just
manufacturing, the same picture of relative incomes holds. In fact, there is a
95% positive correlation between the figures for manufacturing compensation and
for a country’s per capita GDP.[2]
Chart 2 gives a snapshot of global income inequality, based
on a rough estimate of the Lorenz curve for 183 countries comprising 6.7
billion people.[3] World Bank
average GDP per capita data for each country are used as the input. This method
may understate global income inequality, because it assumes that everyone in
country A gets the average per capita income for country A. Nevertheless, it
has the advantage for our purposes of putting the different countries in focus.
Global average GDP per capita in 2011 was $9200. Of the 183
countries included in the data, 124 countries with a population of 5.0 billion
(75% of the world total) had an average income below this, while 104 countries
with a population of 4.8 billion had an average income below $5000 in that
year.
Chart 2: The Global Lorenz Curve, 2011 (based on GDP per capita)
Source and notes: World Bank. Data for average GDP per
capita in 2011 for 183 countries is used as the basis for calculating the
cumulative income distribution curve, the Lorenz curve.
If we take a common measure of inequality, the Gini
coefficient, and calculate this from the data in Chart 2, the figure shows the
expected high level of inequality: close to 66%. It would be more like 70% if
the inequality of component country distributions were also allowed for. In
that case, this measure of income inequality on a global scale is on the same
level as that in the most unequal of countries for which Gini coefficient data
are available: Namibia.
To give specific examples, in 2011 the GDP per capita of Switzerland was put at just over $70,000, while the US number was around $47,000, Germany was $43,000 and the UK was $39,000. Compared to these figures, China was close to $4000 and India to $1300. The data from the World Bank, the IMF, the CIA and other organisations have some differences, and the figures get revised, but the rankings and the income gaps are very similar from all sources.
The basic, and not surprising, fact is that the world
economy is very unequal. When we look at the mechanisms that underpin this
fact, we find that the inequality has much less to do with differences in
labour productivity than with the way that some countries get privileges in the
world economy at the expense of others.
Tony Norfield, 22 May 2012
[1] See BLS Monthly
Labor Review, April 2009. The data noted here are for 2006.
[2] Using the
full set of BLS data for 34 countries’ compensation costs in 2010, I found
there to be a 0.951 correlation coefficient with the respective countries’ per
capita GDP in 2011 as reported by the IMF. This shows that the manufacturing
wage/compensation is closely related to the broader economic income of the
country. This is a sign that the richer, and usually imperialist, countries can
afford to pay their production workers more. As the ‘China price’ article
indicated, this has more to do with imperial power than being based on higher
productivity.
[3] The Lorenz
curve is closely associated with the ‘Gini coefficient’ of inequality mentioned
later. It is a common, summary graphical measure of inequality. The 45-degree
line indicates where 10% of the population gets 10% of the total income, 20%
gets 20% of the total, etc. As such, it represents a line of equality of income
in the population. The divergence of the Lorenz curve from this 45-degree line
shows the extent of inequality. Wikipedia has a general explanation of this
statistical measure and its relationship to the Gini coefficient.
No comments:
Post a Comment