Below are copies of slides from my presentation today to the conference in London on the 150th anniversary of Marx's Capital.
Use them as you wish, but do the decent thing and credit your source if you republish this information elsewhere. The telegrammatic points below are more fully elaborated in other articles on this blog, especially in those on Apple, Amazon and Facebook.
Tony Norfield, 19 September 2017
Showing posts with label equities. Show all posts
Showing posts with label equities. Show all posts
Tuesday, 19 September 2017
Thursday, 24 November 2016
Financial Claims on the World Economy
François Chesnais, Finance
Capital Today: Corporations and Banks in the Lasting Global Slump, Brill,
Leiden, 2016
This book is well worth reading.
It is written in a clear and accessible style and discusses key points about
the limitations of capitalism and the role of contemporary finance. Perhaps its
most important point is how the financial system has accumulated vast claims on
the current and future output of the world economy – in the form of interest
payments on loans and bonds, dividend payments on equities, etc. These claims
have outgrown the ability of the capitalist system to meet them, but government
policy has so far managed to prevent a collapse of financial markets with zero
interest rate policies, quantitative easing, huge deficits in government
spending over taxation, and so forth. The result is an unresolved crisis, a
‘lasting global slump’, in which economic growth remains very weak and vast
debts remain in place.
There are two related points in
his approach to the world economy and finance that distinguish Chesnais from
many other writers, and for which he deserves to be commended. Firstly, he
states clearly that we are in a crisis of capitalism tout court (pp1-2),
not a crisis of ‘financialised’ capitalism – the latter being one that could
presumably be fixed if only the evil financiers were dealt with by a
(capitalist) reforming government. Secondly, he takes ‘the world economy as the
point of departure’ for his analysis, although that is ‘easier said than done’
(p11). While he shows the central role of the US, he avoids the wholly
US-centred analysis common to radical critics of contemporary capitalism, and
instead highlights how the other powers also play a key part in the imperial
machine.
Finance Capital Today
helps the reader’s understanding of the realities of contemporary global
capitalism by providing a wealth of material evidence. It also helps one to
clarify views about what is going on by discussing the theoretical context. In
this review I will highlight the key points raised in the book and also discuss
where I have a number of differences with Chesnais. These differences are
sometimes merely of emphasis, or what may look like simply an alternative
definition of a commonly used term. However, poor formulation of an argument
can also lead to theoretical problems.
Chesnais begins by outlining the
origins of the 2008 crisis, arguing that this had been postponed since 1998 by
the growth of debt in the US and elsewhere, and by the surge of growth in China.
In 2008, ‘the brutality of financial crisis was accounted for by the amount of
fictitious capital accumulated and the degree of vulnerability of the credit
system following securitisation’. The backdrop to the latest phase of crisis
was also one that has made this crisis a global one to a degree unknown to
previous crises (p25). It involved a far more integrated world economy,
following the break up of the USSR and the incorporation of many more countries
into the world trade and financial system. The crisis is one characterised by
‘over-accumulation of capital in the double form of productive capacity leading
to overproduction and of a “plethora of capital” in the form of aspiring
interest-bearing and fictitious capital’. But major governments tried to
prevent the crisis from running its course in the way that occurred in the
1930s (p35).
Within the global set up,
Chesnais has an interesting view of China, which he characterises as not
suffering national domination by the major powers (p43). He notes its
subordinate position in the world division of labour, having offered its cheap
labour workforce up to the world market, but includes this as part of the
development of the world market rather than being a sign of its oppression in
the Leninist sense. This reflects the mixed dimensions of China’s economic and
political status, and one that I would also characterise as being in transition
to the premier league of major powers (China is actually number three in my
ranking of countries by global power).[1]
Chapter 3 is titled ‘The Notion
of Interest-Bearing Capital in the Setting of the Present Centralisation and
Concentration of Capital’. This is an important topic, but one in which
Chesnais’s commendable approach is let down by his exposition. He starts by arguing
that ‘the channelling of surplus value in contemporary capitalism, through both
the holding of government loans and the possession of stock, by a single small
group of highly concentrated financial and non-financial corporations and
private high-income-bracket asset holders, requires that several features of
interest-bearing capital that were treated partly separately by Marx now be
approached in toto’ (p67). I would certainly agree with this, especially
since the relevant section in Capital, Volume 3, is a complete mess, one
that Engels found extremely difficult to edit and to try and salvage. However,
Chesnais does little to develop the argument at this point, and he tends to
keep it focused on banks. Only later in the book does he explain better how
interest-bearing capital is a more universal phenomenon for modern capitalism.
Even then, I would argue that the forms it takes, especially in proprietary
trading, are not fully or well explained by taking interest to be the source of
revenue, or, as he notes from Hilferding, by taking one speculator’s gain as a
loss to another speculator.[2]
This chapter also contains a
discussion of two issues of Marxist theory on finance. One is the difference of
opinion between myself (and others) and Costas Lapavitsas on the question of
banks ‘exploiting’ workers through the charging of interest on loans, etc
(pp76-77). He correctly notes that this interest is, in any event, only a small
portion of bank profits, not the big event claimed by the ‘exploiting’ school.
However, citing Rosa Luxemburg, he comes down on the side of the view that
these deductions are a reduction of the value of labour-power. I
disagree, and not only because Luxemburg’s judgements in matters of economic
theory, let alone political strategy, leave very much to be desired. My
argument, which Chesnais cites, is that the charging of interest does not by
itself suggest a lowering of the value of labour-power. If this interest
deduction became a significant part of workers’ incomes, then wages would tend
to rise to offset this, making it effectively a deduction from corporate
profits. This is not to exclude that the value of labour-power can be forced
down, but it is in the febrile imagination of the anti-finance populists that
this process results from banks charging workers interest on loans.
A second issue of theory raised
in Chapter 3 is on the question of bank lending. In contrast to many other
Marxists, Chesnais recognises that banks can themselves create new deposit
assets. However, he confusingly calls these ‘fictitious capital’ (p84). This is
a relatively common perspective, as seen also in David Harvey’s The Limits
to Capital, but it is not consistent with Marx’s definition. A bank loan
can be created out of thin air by a bank, and is not dependent upon a ‘real’
deposit of cash, so in that sense it is indeed fictitious. But it should then
simply be called a ‘fictitious’ deposit or asset of the bank. Fictitious capital,
by contrast, can most easily be described as a financial security that is traded
in the market and which has a price that is a function of interest rates and
future expectations of returns to the buyer of that security.[3]
That is not true of bank deposit or loan assets, which remain on the bank’s
books. Only if the loan assets later became securitised – that is, when
the loans are the basis for payments made to owners of a tradeable security –
would they become fictitious capital This was the gist of Marx’s definition of
fictitious capital, although one that was not clearly spelled out in Capital
(and neither was his view of bank loans/deposits). To call bank loans or
deposits ‘fictitious capital’ can only lead to confusion when analysing
developments in contemporary financial markets.
Chapter 4 is my favourite of the
whole book. Titled ‘The Organisational Embodiments of Finance Capital and the
Intra-Corporate Division of Surplus Value’, it does not bend to media demands
for a snappy one-liner, but it does provide the reader with valuable
information and analysis. Chesnais discusses the different forms of the
evolution of capitalism in today’s major powers, focusing on Germany, the US,
the UK and France. He examines the relations between the state, private
corporations, banks and imperial power. While noting the importance of pension
funds from the 1990s as major equity owners of big corporations, he argues that
‘rather than bankers, it is industrialists with financial connections that form
the core of the European corporate community’ (p108). Despite some views that
there is an ‘international’ capitalist class, his view, with which I agree, is
that the main groups of ‘finance capitalists’ are domiciled within single
countries.
One important point he makes,
and one that he could have developed more, is how in contemporary capitalism,
by contrast to the views of Marx and Hilferding, merchant capital (essentially
commercial capital and finance) is not subordinate to industry, although it is
dependent upon industrial profit, (p113). However, he does discuss the role of
large commodity traders and retailers. In my view, this reflects the way in
which the major powers have used the financial/commercial system to consolidate
their economic privileges, something that was true for the UK even from the
mid-late nineteenth century. Today, as most people should be aware, it is the
poorer, subordinated countries that do most of the producing, at least in the
non-monopolised fields of production.
In Chapters 5 and 6, Chesnais
covers global oligopolies and the operations of international companies. He reviews
theories of monopolisation and how the development of the European single
market was favourable both for European and for US corporations. There is some
overlap in this material with that covered by John Smith’s book, Imperialism
in the Twenty-First Century (Monthly Review, 2016), with a predatory
appropriation of value by the ‘buyer-driven global commodity chains’ of the
major corporations (p161). However, Chesnais disagrees with Smith’s earlier
work on a number of points, and argues that China, India and Brazil are not in
the classical position of being oppressed countries, having a different, and
higher, status in the world market. On a separate, important point regarding
data on the global economy, Chesnais notes UNCTAD’s estimate that about 80% of
global trade is linked to the international production networks of
international companies, and that it would be wrong to focus on foreign direct
investment data as giving a complete picture of international investment. This
is due both to the blurring of lines between FDI and portfolio investment and
to the importance of offshore centres as the apparent location of the
headquarters of many companies.
Chapter 7 discusses the
globalisation of financial markets and new forms of fictitious capital. This is
a useful review of the growth of financial markets, although it relies very
much on secondary sources, so the data is already several years out of date,
and his coverage of financial derivatives misleadingly characterises them as
being ‘claims on claims’, when derivatives are better described as difference
contracts based on the price of the underlying security to which they refer.
The fundamental point he makes is nevertheless that the apparent diversion of
investment to financial markets has been prompted by the decline in profitable
investment opportunities (p174). The chapter concludes with a review of
financial and (foreign) debt developments in Ecuador, Brazil, Argentina and
South Africa, including the role of ‘vulture funds’ dealing in Argentina’s defaulted
debt.
Chapters 8 and 9 discuss
contemporary developments in financial markets, focusing on banking and credit.
This is well-covered ground, but is useful for those who are less familiar with
recent history, and especially so in explaining the development of
mortgage-backed securities, ‘universal banks’ in Europe, the monopolisation of
banking, shadow banking, etc. There is also a discussion of how ‘leverage’ – ie
borrowing to fund the growth of assets – rose to extreme levels due to the
decline in profitability among financial companies (pp221-). I would note,
however, the publisher’s poor proofreading: ‘over-the-counter’ (OTC) securities
dealing is described as ‘off the counter’ in Chapter 7 and here has the
designation ‘ODT’.[4]
Chapter 10 highlights ‘global
endemic financial instability’ and points out that there is a ‘plethora of
capital in the form of money capital centralised in mutual funds and hedge
funds, bent on valorisation through the holding and trading of fictitious
capital in the form of assets more and more distant from the processes of
surplus value production. Financial profits are harder and harder to earn’
(p245). I would go further and also note how asset managers, pension funds and
insurance companies – far more important investors in financial markets than
hedge funds or mutual funds – are now finding their mountain of assets unable
to generate the returns they have, implicitly or explicitly, promised, although
Chesnais does mention this later in the chapter.
The ‘plethora of capital in the
form of money capital’ is related to the declining profitability of capitalist
investment. Chesnais notes how official reports, from the Bank for
International Settlements, for example, allude to this problem, but also how
they also mix in a description of low productivity growth and low economic
growth in general. He correctly makes the point that the fall in interest rates
long preceded the ‘quantitative easing’ policies that occurred after 2008.[5]
It is difficult to spell out
these relationships empirically, given the available data, and Chesnais does
not try to do this. It is also important to distinguish the rate of interest
from the rate of profit on capital investment, which are two different things.
However, I would suggest a measurement of how much global financial assets have
accumulated – meaning principally equities, bonds and bank loans – against some
measure of absolute global profitability over time. This would measure how far
the financial claims on social resources have grown, in the form of interest
and dividend payments, compared to the surplus revenues available to pay off
these claims. My initial work on this suggests a decline in the rate of return
from 2007 to 2014, whatever the more distorted profitability figures available
for the US alone might say, data that are often used by people wanting a ready
calculation of the ‘rate of profit’. The rate of return I suggest is not a
‘Marxist rate of profit’, as traditionally understood, but it would better
reflect the malaise of the global capitalist system, especially from the
perspective of the major claimants upon its resources, the ones based in the
rich powers!
Chesnais finishes his book with
two themes. One is a lament on the lack of Marxist study in universities and
the lack of journals in which Marxist studies of capitalism can be published.
This is true enough, and I am glad not to have been an undergraduate university
student in the past few decades! Even apparently radical journals such as the
UK’s Cambridge Journal of Economics are basically rather conservative in
outlook, and are dominated by a facile Keynesian approach that dismisses a
Marxist perspective out of hand if it upsets their advocacy of ‘progressive’
policies for the capitalist state to consider. Repeating radical consensus
nonsense will get a pass; revealing the imperial mechanism of power has to jump
a hundred hurdles to be an acceptable journal article. Such is the almost
universal climate in academia today, despite the evidently destructive outcomes
from the system they claim to be analysing.[6]
Ironically, this is why the most trenchant and incisive critiques of capitalism
today – at least from a descriptive point of view – often come from analysts
working in the financial markets. They have to tell their clients what is
really going on!
Friends have suggested to me
that the situation for critical academics is even worse in the US, something I
find easy to believe. I have some knowledge of, and better hope for, the
development of a more critical intellectual climate coming from outside the
Anglosphere. This should not be too difficult to achieve.
The second concluding remark by
Chesnais is the question of how a new phase of capital accumulation might
emerge. There is the plethora of (fictitious) capital with its claims on social
revenue that cannot be met, but which, on the other hand, has not been devalued
in a crisis collapse, because the major governments have done their best to
prevent it, fearing the consequences. Chesnais discusses technical innovation
to some extent, but sees this as being overshadowed by capital’s degradation of
the environment. One is left with the ‘notion of barbarism, associated with the
two World Wars and the Holocaust’ (p267). That is a downbeat but telling point
about the progress of opposition to imperialism today. In the main imperial
countries, the answer to the question of ‘Socialism or Barbarism’ is biased in
favour of the latter.
Finishing on a more general
comment, my own preference is to avoid the term ‘finance capital’ completely,
whereas the book is titled Finance Capital Today. The term is associated
with Hilferding and used by Lenin, but the definition is too bound up with
Hilferding’s notion that banks control industry. This was not a good
description of the situation in the early 20th century, and is far less true
today. Chesnais would accept this and instead defines ‘finance capital’ as the
‘simultaneous and intertwined concentration and centralisation of money
capital, industrial capital and merchant or commercial capital as an outcome of
domestic and transnational concentration through mergers and acquisitions’
(p5). He explains how the different forms of finance capital evolved in
different countries, making an important distinction between the privileges of
the major powers and the subordinate position of others. I would go along with
this definition, but I would argue for putting fictitious capital at the
centre of attention, not ‘finance capital’. This would show more clearly that
what Marx called the ‘law of value’ is today mainly expressed, or at least
expressed more directly, via the markets for financial securities,
rather than in the markets for commodities, although the latter are of course
important. A company’s ability to access funds and at what cost, via the equity
market or bond market, or a government’s ability to borrow and spend, is each
signalled by the markets for their securities. These markets show what is good,
bad and acceptable in the imperialist world economy today.
Tony Norfield, 24 November 2016
[1] See my book,
The City: London and the Global Power of Finance, Verso, 2016, p111.
[2] The City,
pp144-147.
[3] For an
explanation, see The City, pp83-92.
[4] The book is
expensively priced, so order it for your library! The book
will be cheaper when later published in paperback, however.
[6] It works
like this. Academic journals are graded according to their supposed value, and
getting an article published in a highly ranked journal is the objective of all
academics. Think what you like about the journal’s real worth, these grades are
important for the scores achieved by contributors in the assessment they get
from their universities, and, most importantly, in the assessment of their
universities for government funding purposes. Over recent decades, this has led
to a small group of mainstream, conservative, uncritical journals becoming the
favoured destination for research articles, which in turn means that academics
orient their work to what these journals will accept. It is a machine for
generating very little worth reading, and also a system for maintaining a
conservative status quo. That system is further maintained by a journal
editorial board and a group of ‘peer reviewers’ with the same general outlook.
A similar mechanism also leads academics to have absurdly long bibliographies
and excessive citations in their articles, since citing their friends will
encourage the return favour, and citations are another means by which academic
value is assessed.
Labels:
academic,
banks,
bonds,
China,
equities,
FDI,
fictitious capital,
finance capital,
Financialisation,
France,
Francois Chesnais,
Germany,
interest,
John Smith,
portfolio investment,
profits,
securitisation,
UK,
US
Monday, 25 January 2016
The City: London and the Global Power of Finance
My new book, The City: London
and the Global Power of Finance, will be published by Verso Books on 12
April 2016. Below I note reviews that it has received so far and give a
full list of the contents. Details for ordering the book, which will be
available both in hardback (price £20 or less) and as an ebook (around £14), are available on the Verso website
and on Amazon.
-----
“Tony Norfield has provided a
strikingly original take on the international financial system by placing it
systematically within the world imperialist structure of power. He rejects the currently
fashionable path of interpreting the ascent of finance by looking at how the
leading financial sector agents, operating by way of banks, hedge funds,
private equity firms, and the like, manipulate the political-economic game to
increase their own personal wealth, while downplaying any useful economic
functions they might be fulfilling. He insists, on the contrary, that finance
be understood as a form of power deriving from the economic-cum political
capacity to compete at the highest levels of global capitalism, which
simultaneously endows a limited group of countries and corporations
disproportionate access to the world s resources and operates as the system's
indispensable nerve center. Norfield's unusual clarity as both an analyst and
expositor is reflected in his ability to lay out for his readers an
easy-to-grasp introduction to how finance works today in the process of
offering a detailed historically-rooted account of the multiple hierarchies and
privileged relationships through which global economic domination is
constructed and reproduced. The City is a tour de force, which will soon be
recognized as a formidable challenge to conventional wisdom and an essential
contribution in its own right.”
Robert Brenner, author of The Economics of Global Turbulence
“This book does the seemingly impossible:
rendering finance's mysteries transparent to the average reader, and at the
same time delivering a penetrating analysis of the global economic system that
will enlighten even experts. Tony Norfield has written a truly exciting and
important book.”
Paul Mattick, author of Business
as Usual
"It is not every day you read a book about global finance by a banker who quotes Lenin approvingly on page two. Unlike many of those who produce Marxist critiques of financial capitalism, Norfield writes from a position of experience: he has worked in the belly of the beast, and the book is the better for it... Just after the financial crisis, Rolling Stone magazine called Goldman Sachs the “vampire squid wrapped around the face of humanity”. In this book, Norfield extends the metaphor to call London the “vampire’s blood bank”. In The City, he has done the research and pulled together the financial statistics that explain how the bloodsucking works.”
Brooke Masters, Financial Times*
“The City is a valuable addition to the critical analysis of the financialisation of our world. And Tony Norfield is an experienced and radical guide to London's role in this process. This book should be required reading for both bankers and activists alike.”
Joris Luyendjik, author of Swimming
with Sharks: My Journey into the World of the Bankers
TABLE OF CONTENTS
Preface
Chapter 1 Britain, Finance and the World
Economy
World economic and financial
power
Britain’s invisible empire
Understanding finance and
imperialism
Insights, conspiracies and
policy contingencies
The ‘End of History’ revisited
History
wakes up
‘New
Deal’ and no deal
The system
Chapter 2 The Anglo-American System
British or American finance?
Anglo-American financial
relationships in transition
Building beyond the Empire
New York versus London
The Anglo-American euromarket
British capitalism, finance and
official policy
Eurobonds and London’s
international role
Historical logic
Chapter 3 Finance and the Major Powers
Regime change
British imperial strategy and
the pound
State policy on financial
markets from 1979
Finance and the major powers
Gravity and the global system
Chapter 4 Power and Parasitism
Money-capitalists and financial
institutions
Interest-bearing capital
Banks
Brokers
Asset managers
Insurance companies
Pension funds
Bank credit creation
Financial securities and
economic power
The flexible noose
Finance and the rule of capital
Financial parasitism
Global parasitism, investment,
trade and finance
Who reaps the returns?
Finance as a normal part of the
system
Chapter 5 The World Hierarchy
The premier league
Capitalism and the state
The state and finance
Monopoly and imperialism
Monopoly today
World projection of power
Chapter 6 Profit and Finance
Return on equity and leverage
Comparing profits
Financial assets and derivatives
Financial revenues, surplus
value and securities
Trading revenues
The rate of profit and capital’s
limits
Outcomes
Profits, financial and global
developments
Moribund capitalism
Chapter 7 The Imperial Web
Currency, trade and seigniorage
‘Exorbitant privilege’
Running the world banking
system: US dollar power
Financial services exports
Equity markets, financial power
and control
Carving up the market
The daily grind
Chapter 8 Inside the Machine
Number crunching
The surplus from City dealing
Global capitalism’s financial
broker
UK financial account: FDI,
portfolio flows and bank funding
UK assets, liabilities and
returns
The City’s global network, tax
havens and global finance
Nice work, if you can get it
Chapter 9 Eternal Interests, Temporary Allies
‘Open for business’
Economics and domestic politics
Islamic finance and the City
China, BRICS and the Anglo-American system
Finance and the rule of capital
List of Tables
3.1 UK, Germany, France – patterns of trade, 1980 and 90 (% of
total)
3.2 Financial market shares of major powers, 1980-2001 (% of
total)
5.1 Corporate control by controlling company, 2007
6.1 UK monetary financial institutions’ financial balance sheet
7.1 Financial services export revenues, 2000-2013
7.2 Equity market capitalisation and turnover, 2013
8.1 UK current account balance and components, 1987-2014
8.2 External positions of banks, end-2014
8.3 Foreign exchange turnover, 1995-2013
8.4 OTC interest rate derivatives turnover, April 2013
8.5 UK financial account net annual flows, 1987-2014
8.6 Net external position of UK MFIs by location
List of Charts
5.1 The global pecking order, 2013-2014
6.1 Leverage ratios of major international banks, 2007–2011
6.2 Leverage ratios of major UK banks, 1960-2010
6.3 US corporate rate of profit, 1948-2013
6.4 US Federal Reserve financial support stays in place
8.1 Key components of the UK current account, 1987-2014
8.2 UK net foreign investment stock position, 1989-2014
8.3 Returns on UK foreign investment assets and liabilities,
1990-2014
* note of the FT review was added on 8 May 2016
Labels:
Anglo-American system,
banks,
bonds,
BRICS,
China,
equities,
finance,
FX,
Imperialism,
leverage,
Monopoly,
parasitism,
profits,
tax havens,
The City of London,
trading,
UK,
US
Friday, 22 January 2016
Oil Prices, Equities and Debt
Equity markets have begun 2016
with the biggest falls on record, while the price of a barrel of oil dropped
below $30. This is more than just a coincidence. The fall in oil prices results
from, and also exacerbates, the continued malaise in the world economy
At first sight, lower oil prices
should merely redistribute income from producers to consumers, via the lower of
cost of energy, transport, etc. What is such a disaster about that, at least
from the point of view of the world economy as a whole? One problem is the
different concentration of the losses and gains: a small number of producers
lose a lot, while many millions of consumers gain only a little. So news
headlines report cancelled investment projects and job losses, rather than the
motorist at the petrol station saving pennies on a litre of fuel. The negative
impact on producers, especially on their investment, could well outweigh the
demand that might result from consumers spending on other things. For example,
many huge investments in shale production that looked viable when a barrel of
oil was priced at $100 or above now look unprofitable – at least the loans
given to these companies now look poorly backed by their prospects.
What is often overlooked, even
by ‘Keynesian’ advocates of demand management, is that although consumer
spending is bigger than investment in the economy, the swings in investment
spending are much bigger than the percentage changes in consumption, and
usually lead the up and down cycles of demand. Furthermore, what such analysts always
overlook is that investment spending is basically driven by potential
profitability. But this should not be a surprise in a capitalist economy!
More importantly, all this takes
place in the context of continued, huge levels of debt compared to what the
economy produces. There has been a sharp rise in debt levels versus GDP between 2007, ‘pre-crisis’,
and 2014. This had occurred for almost all countries: poor countries such as
China saw the sharpest rises in debt ratios; but rich countries saw a further
increase from already elevated levels. This is the important context for the
apparent reaction of equity markets to the fall in oil prices. The underlying
problem is that debts cannot be paid back. It does not matter that the increase in debt in richer countries between 2007 and 2014 has largely been borne by the government, as the public sector took on private liabilities - all this means is that the pressure for austerity via cuts in government spending is all the greater. This casts doubt on the value
of the full range of financial securities. Those securities linked to oil and
gas prices now get hit directly because there is a clear focus of potential
loss that is visible every second of the financial trading day. But the myriad
of other equity securities issued by other financial, industrial and commercial
companies get caught up in the downward vortex. This is not only because money
capitalists work on the basis of what looks like giving the most attractive yield,
so a fall in energy-related security prices has a knock on effect on other,
non-energy-related securities too. More troubling is that there is clearly a
broader problem affecting the whole economy.
This problem of debt and
insufficient incentive to boost production overwhelms the otherwise mixed, plus
and minus economic outcome (mainly plus) that follows from lower oil prices. In
the oil market, refiners will be making more profit as the cost of their
feedstock falls with lower crude oil prices faster than will their output
prices of refined products. To some extent, this will insulate the integrated
oil corporations from the downturn. Airline and other travel companies will
also benefit from lower energy costs. So will China and Japan, major consumers
of oil, although their energy companies will suffer. Nevertheless, governments,
from Russia, Iran and Venezuela to Saudi Arabia, Norway and the UK will find
their oil and gas tax revenues falling. This has already led Saudi Arabia to
make very sharp cutbacks in its public spending to reduce a dramatically high
deficit, while other countries have seen a drop in their currency exchange
rates.
Table 1: Core Debt Levels of Non-Financial Sectors as a % of GDP, 2007 and 2014
Source: BIS, Quarterly Report, September 2015
Table 1: Core Debt Levels of Non-Financial Sectors as a % of GDP, 2007 and 2014
Source: BIS, Quarterly Report, September 2015
All of this might simply be a series of local difficulties offset by positive developments elsewhere. But, in the absence of any momentum to support profitable capitalist investment elsewhere, it results in continued capitalist stagnation and the promise of yet more government measures to prevent a collapse of their system.
Tony Norfield, 22 January 2016
Thursday, 22 January 2015
Europe Gets Even More QuEasy
Today the European Central Bank
did what financial markets had expected, after lots of leaking of the policy
moves. They announced they would buy securities in the asset markets, at a rate
a little higher than had been expected of €60 billion per month, from March
2015. The policy will continue until inflation looks like getting closer to 2%,
which, with the slump in energy prices, will be a while yet. In all likelihood,
this extra asset buying (there has been some before) will amount to a bit over
€1 trillion and last until September 2016, maybe longer. For comparison's sake,
the new policy is around 10% of euro area GDP, compared to the US and UK
policies of 'quantitative easing' that have amounted to more than 20% of GDP.
This policy move is the latest
in a series that indicate there is no way out of the crisis. How can anyone
believe that this policy, essentially making government bonds have even lower
yields, can do anything for the economy when 10-year government borrowing costs
were already less than 1% in Germany and France and less than 2% in
Italy and Spain, the euro area's biggest economies?
The central bank's notion is
that this will feed into private sector borrowing costs being lower, but there
are some difficulties here. One is that there is very little demand to borrow
to invest, given the dire economic outlook; the other is that banks would not
to lend at anything like the sub-1% or 2% numbers to private investors, and the
level of interest rates is not the problem. The problem is that there is no
profitable avenue for large-scale capital investment, or any investment that
does not depend upon government subsidy, tax dodging or some form of financial
trickery. Even the countries that claim they have done better than the euro
average - especially the US, but also the UK and Switzerland - are now faced
with higher currency values against the ones that are under the market's cosh. Last week, the Swiss National Bank's made a dramatic move to abandon its 3-year attempt to stabilise its currency against the euro. This was done largely in anticipation of this week's action by the ECB and so far the euro's value has fallen 18% against the Swiss franc. Unsurprisingly, the euro fell another 1-2% today.
The ECB made a concession to
German worries about the new policy. They said that 80% of the risk of the new
purchases would be borne by national central banks, because central banks in the euro area might
buy rubbish and face a loss. In its
press releases today, they did not explain who would buy what, or how much.
Because the scale of the buying, if it is not directed, would evidently be
concentrated on the better risks - Germany, especially - a proviso was
included: only up to one-third of a country's outstanding debt could be bought
in this way, and the debt had to have a maturity of 2-30 years. Germany has
around €1.1 trillion of debt outstanding, with less than this in the 2-30
maturity range. So these, the 'safest assets', will not be able to use up more
than about a third of the new programme. German government securities out to a
maturity of 5 years also have a yield that is zero or negative. So, presumably,
this is good news for the government securities of France, Italy and Spain, the
other countries with large bond markets.
The ECB's hope is that the lower
yields will force investors to take on more economy-boosting risks. Instead,
the likelihood is that there will be a continued reliance by capitalists on
'making money' through financial investment, something that further stretches
the gap between value creation and financial accounting. On occasion, that gap is
narrowed by a slump of financial market prices for bonds and/or equities, but
the ECB has signalled that it will gamble for a while longer on trying to push
the gap still wider.
Tony Norfield, 22 January 2015
Labels:
bonds,
ECB,
equities,
euro,
Europe,
Germany,
Italy,
negative yields,
quantitative easing,
Spain,
Switzerland,
UK,
US
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)